Haver Analytics
Haver Analytics
Global| Sep 08 2020

"Averaging" Inflation Does Not Eliminate The Flaws In The Fed's Policy Approach; It Compounds Them

Summary

Federal Reserve has spent over a year conducting a review of its monetary policy strategy, tools, and communication process. The review was an academic re-assessment of an academic experiment called inflation targeting. The new [...]


Federal Reserve has spent over a year conducting a review of its monetary policy strategy, tools, and communication process. The review was an academic re-assessment of an academic experiment called inflation targeting. The new framework of inflation averaging is an extension of the inflation-targeting regime, with a longer timeline.

This decision on inflation targeting moves monetary policy closer to a rule-based framework. A rule-based framework creates the premise that there are no legitimate objectives besides the item being targeted.

Inflation targeting was never supposed to become a rule-based framework. Proponents of the practice argued it would help increase the "transparency" of conventional monetary policy and emphasize the commitment toward maintaining a low and steady inflation environment.

Inflation targeting has never delivered the macroeconomic results that were promised. That's because it has no practical foundation, focuses on a narrow set of prices that are not entirely market-determined, and creates an uneven playing field between the economy and finance. Inflation averaging will compound the errors.

First, mandating an inflation rate of 2% has no theoretical justification.

There is no such thing as an "ideal" or steady rate of inflation. Policymakers have never offered any empirical evidence to justify a 2% inflation target because none exists.

Research and actual experiences show that an inflation rate too high or too low for an extended period can create imbalances and bad economic outcomes. But that range is very wide.

In the mid-to-late 1990s reported core consumer price inflation averaged more than 100 basis points above the inflation rate of the last decade and the macro performance in terms of growth, job creation and wage gains was far superior.

Policymakers have the freedom to change their operating framework. But any framework should be grounded with solid research and not made up with "alternative" facts to support its use as a policy tool.

Second, inflation targeting falsely assumes there is absolute perfection in price measurement.

Subtle changes in the prices and quality of goods and services make price measurement at times a "best guess". Every year government statisticians face new products, changes in old products, shifts in demand, and company pricing strategies.

One of the most complex issues in price measurement is the pervasiveness of item replacements. Item replacement refers to a process whereby government statisticians must select and price a different product because the one previously included could not be found. Previous studies have found that some items are replaced more than once a year and annual replacement rates could be as high as 30% for products.

But item replacements are uneven year-to-year and therefore so too is the judgment component of reported inflation. As a result, price changes that are down or up a tenth or a quarter of a percent from year to the next should be considered nothing but statistical noise. But a rule-based inflation-targeting framework will compel policymakers to fiddle with the stance of policy to account for the noise in price measurement.

How is it that policymakers nowadays have fallen in the trap of placing so much importance on a single statistic to conduct monetary policy?

Third, the Fed's inflation-targeting regime mistakes indirect measures of inflation for direct ones.

A critical aspect of the design of price targeting is the selection of the price series. The price series must be timely and a direct measure of inflation.

The consumer price index (CPI) is the only direct measure of consumer prices. But policymakers have opted to use the personal consumption deflator (PCE). The PCE deflator is not a direct measure of prices since 70% of the prices come from the CPI. The other 30% is based on non-market prices.

Four of the past 5 years, the core CPI has exceeded the 2% target. The only year it missed was 2018 when it was 1.8%. That small undershoot from the 2% target is not statistically significant and certainty not large enough to trigger a change in the stance of monetary policy.

Over the same 5-year period, core PCE ran nearly 75 basis points below the core CPI rate. Almost all of that difference can be explained by the "invisible" prices, or prices for items that are in the PCE but not in CPI.

Does it make sense to base policy decisions on "invisible" prices?

Fourth, inflation targeting lacks balance in anchoring consumer inflation expectations with investor expectations.

The announcement of an inflation target is intended to reduce uncertainty over the future course of inflation and anchor people's inflation expectations. It is hard to prove that the formal announcement of inflation targeting has had any impact on people's inflation expectations.

According to the University of Michigan's consumer sentiment survey, people's one-year inflation expectations have fluctuated between 2.5% and 3% for the past 20 years, moving above or below the range during an economic crisis or oil shocks. Perhaps people are unaware of the Fed's 2% inflation target or that "experienced" inflation consistently higher than reported inflation.

But investors are readily aware of the Fed's inflation target. Every little tweak in the Fed's policy statement on inflation and its impact on official rates triggers almost an instant reaction on the part of investors.

One of the inherent weaknesses of inflation targeting is the inability to balance consumer and investor expectations. That is, as policymakers attempt to simultaneously hit an arbitrary price target and anchor inflation expectations they are inadvertently un-anchoring investor expectations as it eliminates the fear of higher interest rates, encouraging extreme speculation and risk-taking in the financial markets.

Why do policymakers only focus on people's inflation expectations and not people's/investor's asset price expectations as well since both have become unstable at times resulting in bad economic outcomes?

Informal and formal price targeting has been in the Fed's tool kit for the past 25 years or so. The effects on income and portfolio flows are not similar to conventional monetary policy. At the end of 2019, the market value of equities in people's portfolios stood at 3X times workers income, up from 1X times in the mid-1990s.

The shift to inflation averaging compounds the unevenness. That's because inflation averaging will extend the period of low-interest rates, encouraging more speculation and risk, increasing gains in finance over the economy.

A critical review of the pros and con's inflation targeting will have to wait for the next crisis. It usually takes three crises before policymakers realize something is fundamentally wrong with their framework.

By then there will be a number of new academic papers that will highlight the flaws of inflation targeting/averaging, expanding on those that are listed in this article while adding others as well.

Viewpoint commentaries are the opinions of the author and do not reflect the views of Haver Analytics.
  • Joseph G. Carson, Former Director of Global Economic Research, Alliance Bernstein.   Joseph G. Carson joined Alliance Bernstein in 2001. He oversaw the Economic Analysis team for Alliance Bernstein Fixed Income and has primary responsibility for the economic and interest-rate analysis of the US. Previously, Carson was chief economist of the Americas for UBS Warburg, where he was primarily responsible for forecasting the US economy and interest rates. From 1996 to 1999, he was chief US economist at Deutsche Bank. While there, Carson was named to the Institutional Investor All-Star Team for Fixed Income and ranked as one of Best Analysts and Economists by The Global Investor Fixed Income Survey. He began his professional career in 1977 as a staff economist for the chief economist’s office in the US Department of Commerce, where he was designated the department’s representative at the Council on Wage and Price Stability during President Carter’s voluntary wage and price guidelines program. In 1979, Carson joined General Motors as an analyst. He held a variety of roles at GM, including chief forecaster for North America and chief analyst in charge of production recommendations for the Truck Group. From 1981 to 1986, Carson served as vice president and senior economist for the Capital Markets Economics Group at Merrill Lynch. In 1986, he joined Chemical Bank; he later became its chief economist. From 1992 to 1996, Carson served as chief economist at Dean Witter, where he sat on the investment-policy and stock-selection committees.   He received his BA and MA from Youngstown State University and did his PhD coursework at George Washington University. Honorary Doctorate Degree, Business Administration Youngstown State University 2016. Location: New York.

    More in Author Profile »

More Viewpoints