Haver Analytics
Haver Analytics
Global| Apr 16 2021

Fed's Inflation Problem: Easy Money Creates More Market Than Reported Inflation

Summary

The Fed has an inflation problem, but it's not the failure to meet an arbitrary target. The problem is that there is a significant separation between reported and market inflation. The uncoupling is not new and is a statistical issue. [...]


The Fed has an inflation problem, but it's not the failure to meet an arbitrary target. The problem is that there is a significant separation between reported and market inflation. The uncoupling is not new and is a statistical issue. But it has become a thorny policy problem as easy money creates more market than reported inflation.

Statistical Separation---Reported Versus Market Inflation

In practice, there should be no difference between reported and market inflation. But in the statistical business of measuring and reporting consumer price inflation (CPI), there is.

Market prices reflect current economic conditions and measure what the consumer would pay, and businesses receive. That is how prices for goods and services are measured and reported in the consumer price index, except for one.

Price estimates for owner-occupied housing (which accounts for roughly one-quarter of the CPI) do not reflect market prices, nor are they based on data for owner-occupied homes. In the CPI, owner-occupied home costs are estimated based on what people could have earned had they rented their house.

However, since the late 1990s, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) has been using rents of primary residence as a proxy for the implied rent for owner-occupied housing, even though the markets' characteristics and price trends are fundamentally different.

Two decades of rents and house price data show the scale of separation between reported and market inflation when statisticians use the data from one market to measure prices in another one.

That was most obvious during the housing bubble of the 2000s, but it is also apparent today. For example, in the middle of the housing bubble in 2005, the house price index reported by the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA) increased 10.4%, or 100 basis points faster than the prior year. But the CPI owner-rent series was only up 2.3%, unchanged from the rent inflation rate of 2004. A similar separation between house prices and owner rents is occurring today. In the past 12 months, the FHFA house price index is up 12%, and owners rent is up 2%

Rent inflation should reflect supply and demand factors more than anything else. However, during robust housing markets and a dwindling supply of homes available for rent, the CPI shows a deceleration in owner-occupied housing rent inflation. Why? Because government statisticians use data from the rental market that reflect different supply and demand factors.

The statistical separation between reported and market inflation has become a policy problem. Policymakers claim that rising housing prices are a "win" for monetary policy but fail to realize that easy money creates more market inflation than reported inflation. The burst of market house prices and not estimated rent prices triggered the housing market collapse in the 2000s.

Market prices reflect the allocative decisions of the consumer. Those prices are the signals through which monetary policy needs to gauge its policy stance. The Fed's inflation problem stems from its failure to distinguish between reported and market inflation. There is zero chance that a "bubble" will ever exist in implied rents or damage the real economy, as it is an artificial price with no buyers or sellers. Market bubbles are the big ones as they have caused significant adverse economic outcomes.

Viewpoint commentaries are the opinions of the author and do not reflect the views of Haver Analytics.
  • Joseph G. Carson, Former Director of Global Economic Research, Alliance Bernstein.   Joseph G. Carson joined Alliance Bernstein in 2001. He oversaw the Economic Analysis team for Alliance Bernstein Fixed Income and has primary responsibility for the economic and interest-rate analysis of the US. Previously, Carson was chief economist of the Americas for UBS Warburg, where he was primarily responsible for forecasting the US economy and interest rates. From 1996 to 1999, he was chief US economist at Deutsche Bank. While there, Carson was named to the Institutional Investor All-Star Team for Fixed Income and ranked as one of Best Analysts and Economists by The Global Investor Fixed Income Survey. He began his professional career in 1977 as a staff economist for the chief economist’s office in the US Department of Commerce, where he was designated the department’s representative at the Council on Wage and Price Stability during President Carter’s voluntary wage and price guidelines program. In 1979, Carson joined General Motors as an analyst. He held a variety of roles at GM, including chief forecaster for North America and chief analyst in charge of production recommendations for the Truck Group. From 1981 to 1986, Carson served as vice president and senior economist for the Capital Markets Economics Group at Merrill Lynch. In 1986, he joined Chemical Bank; he later became its chief economist. From 1992 to 1996, Carson served as chief economist at Dean Witter, where he sat on the investment-policy and stock-selection committees.   He received his BA and MA from Youngstown State University and did his PhD coursework at George Washington University. Honorary Doctorate Degree, Business Administration Youngstown State University 2016. Location: New York.

    More in Author Profile »

More Viewpoints