Haver Analytics
Haver Analytics
Global| Aug 28 2020

"Buying" More Inflation Is A Policy Mistake

Summary

The Federal Reserve's new policy of inflation "averaging" is a mistake. The trade-off nowadays is between inflation and financial stability. Buying more inflation will eventually create financial imbalances that over time will [...]


The Federal Reserve's new policy of inflation "averaging" is a mistake. The trade-off nowadays is between inflation and financial stability. Buying more inflation will eventually create financial imbalances that over time will undermine the economic performance policymakers are trying to create.

The parallel to this is the misguided policies of the 1970s. Back then policymakers found buying more employment with a little more inflation did not work.

Facts Don't Support Policy Change

Federal Reserve policymaker's argument for the policy change is that consumer inflation has been consistently running below its 2% target. Also, sustained low inflation readings can over time depress inflation expectations, which can create "ever lower inflation and inflation expectations". The evidence does not support these arguments.

The Federal Reserve statistical branches publish two measures of consumer price inflation. The Bureau of Labor Statistics publishes the consumer price index (CPI) and the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) publishes the personal consumption deflator (PCE).

CPI is the basic measure of consumer price inflation. The PCE measure gets 70% of its price data from the CPI. But the PCE also includes items or services provided to consumers by businesses and government. BEA uses a lot of imputations (non-market prices) to value these items and services since these items are not "sold" to the consumer.

In the 4 of the past 5 years, core CPI has been running above the Fed's 2% target. The only year of the past 5 when core CPI ran below 2% was 2017 when it ran 1.8%. That small shortfall is not statistically significant and surely does not warrant a fundamental change in policy.

Policymakers favor the PCE over the CPI. But the fact that the core PCE inflation is running below core CPI is because of the use of "imputations" or non-market prices. It makes little sense to base an inflation policy on non-market prices.

Also, the argument the low reported inflation is undermining consumer inflation expectations is not supported by the facts. Consumer's one-year inflation expectations from the University of Michigan consumer sentiment survey shows that people's inflation expectations have consistently run above-reported inflation and the 2% target.

In the past two decades, the only times' consumer inflation expectations dropped below 2% was during 9/11 and the Great Financial Crisis. And each drop in expectations was short-lived. Consumer inflation expectations currently stand at 3%.

The Federal Reserve has three mandates, maximum employment, price stability, and financial stability. Financial stability is often overlooked or ignored. The last two recessions were triggered not by inflation running too high or too low, but by real and financial asset prices running too hot. Current macro valuations asset valuations now exceed the high thresholds of the last two asset bubbles.

Changes in monetary policy often have unintended consequences. Trying to buy more inflation is a mistake. It's a policy mistake because actual inflation has been running above target. But the bigger problem is that the new policy promises low-interest rates for long periods. That invites more speculation and risks in finance at a time when asset values are already at nosebleed levels.

The misguided policies of the 1970s eventually ended with an economic crash that last nearly three years. Will this time play out differently? I have my doubts. Creating a low -interest policy to "buy" more general inflation does not guarantee any more inflation, but it will elevate asset values more. Separating finance from the economy has shown during the tech and housing bubbles to be as problematic as the inflation imbalance of yesteryear.

Viewpoint commentaries are the opinions of the author and do not reflect the views of Haver Analytics.
  • Joseph G. Carson, Former Director of Global Economic Research, Alliance Bernstein.   Joseph G. Carson joined Alliance Bernstein in 2001. He oversaw the Economic Analysis team for Alliance Bernstein Fixed Income and has primary responsibility for the economic and interest-rate analysis of the US. Previously, Carson was chief economist of the Americas for UBS Warburg, where he was primarily responsible for forecasting the US economy and interest rates. From 1996 to 1999, he was chief US economist at Deutsche Bank. While there, Carson was named to the Institutional Investor All-Star Team for Fixed Income and ranked as one of Best Analysts and Economists by The Global Investor Fixed Income Survey. He began his professional career in 1977 as a staff economist for the chief economist’s office in the US Department of Commerce, where he was designated the department’s representative at the Council on Wage and Price Stability during President Carter’s voluntary wage and price guidelines program. In 1979, Carson joined General Motors as an analyst. He held a variety of roles at GM, including chief forecaster for North America and chief analyst in charge of production recommendations for the Truck Group. From 1981 to 1986, Carson served as vice president and senior economist for the Capital Markets Economics Group at Merrill Lynch. In 1986, he joined Chemical Bank; he later became its chief economist. From 1992 to 1996, Carson served as chief economist at Dean Witter, where he sat on the investment-policy and stock-selection committees.   He received his BA and MA from Youngstown State University and did his PhD coursework at George Washington University. Honorary Doctorate Degree, Business Administration Youngstown State University 2016. Location: New York.

    More in Author Profile »

More Viewpoints