Haver Analytics
Haver Analytics
Global| Oct 15 2018

Financial Stability Needs Rules Too!

Summary

The sharp sell-off in equity prices is no reason for the Federal Reserve to abandon its plan to continue to raise official interest rates, but it does highlight the need for policymakers to offer better clarity, if not establish some [...]


The sharp sell-off in equity prices is no reason for the Federal Reserve to abandon its plan to continue to raise official interest rates, but it does highlight the need for policymakers to offer better clarity, if not establish some guidelines, on its role in maintaining financial stability.

Business cycles have become increasingly dominated by asset price cycles such that financial stability has become more than an equal alongside full employment and stable prices in the objectives of monetary policy. As a result, policymakers may need to set some rules and be willing to use the interest rate lever, which has been traditionally used for fighting inflation, to address excessive asset valuations and easy financial conditions so that a quick unwind of the financial cycle does not destabilize the economic cycle as it did twice before.

Monetary policy has long been focused on the economic cycle because of its dual mandate of full employment and price stability. And in recent years policymakers have altered the policy framework to include specific price targets as well as communicate its policy objectives through its economic and official rate forecasts. The maintenance of price stability is believed to be paramount for a successful monetary policy and policymakers believe by publically setting a specific price target (in this case a 2% increase in consumer price inflation) it provides an anchor to the public’s price expectations.

Yet, people’s expectations of price inflation are largely driven by local events and experiences. As a result, it is hard to see how there is any “herding” of consumer price expectations based on the Fed’s official target and that the fact that the sum of the local inflation results add up to something close to aggregate consumer price target of 2% is based on more luck than design.

Monetary policy appears to have a more direct impact on price expectations in the asset markets where there is clear evidence of “herd behavior” among investors. And recent changes in monetary policy operating framework appear to have increased the “herding bias” in the asset markets.

For example, as policymakers have become more transparent and communicate their economic forecasts as well as the scale and timing of policy rate changes the risk of investing has been greatly reduced since the odds of a potential negative “policy surprise” have been cut to almost zero. Policymakers have also shown consistent bias of responding with a lowering official rates when there is a sharp and sustained decline in asset prices, and conversely have not used the interest rate lever when asset prices have risen a lot over a period of time. All of this invites lowered risk premiums while encouraging speculation in riskier assets.

No one is arguing that policymakers establish a “speed limit” to asset prices, but two asset bubbles in the past 20 years indicate that there needs to be an increased focus on financial conditions and the elevated level of asset prices. Lessons from past asset bubbles offer some guidelines when asset markets have become unhinged and “frothy” and therefore become a key risk to the economy at large.

At the end of the third quarter, for example, the market value of household real and financial assets reached two record highs; 6.1 times the level of nominal GDP and over 700% of disposable income, far exceeding the prior peaks recorded during equity and housing bubbles. These elevated level of asset vales should at least send a ‘warning signal” to policymakers that by holding official rates at very low levels for an unprecedented period they inadvertently created too much liquidity and too easy of financial conditions.

Policymakers have long argued against using the interest rate lever to address rich asset valuations (bubbles), as they believe it would cause too much damage to the general economy. Yet, the evidence to suggest that policymakers can’t use the interest rate lever to address frothy financial conditions and asset bubbles without causing substantial damage to the economy is sketchy at best, but there is hard evidence (two recessions) of what happens to the general economy if policymakers let asset price cycles driven by excessive liquidity go unattended.

As the nature of economic and finance cycles have changes the conduct of monetary policy has to involve and incorporate more elements of risk management in its deliberations, and not just base policy decisions on the dual mandate of full employment and price stability. Policymakers would be wise to establish some guidelines on its role in maintaining financial stability and be willing to use the interest rate lever in the pursuit of financial stability.

In his speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City symposium at Jackson Hole in August Federal Reserve Chairman Jerome Powell stated, “In the run-up to the past two recessions, destabilizing excesses appeared mainly in the financial markets rather than in inflation.” The fact that the market value of household assets relative to income and output has already surpassed the peak levels of the past two cycles suggest potentially destabilizing excesses already exist.

Viewpoint commentaries are the opinions of the author and do not reflect the views of Haver Analytics.
  • Joseph G. Carson, Former Director of Global Economic Research, Alliance Bernstein.   Joseph G. Carson joined Alliance Bernstein in 2001. He oversaw the Economic Analysis team for Alliance Bernstein Fixed Income and has primary responsibility for the economic and interest-rate analysis of the US. Previously, Carson was chief economist of the Americas for UBS Warburg, where he was primarily responsible for forecasting the US economy and interest rates. From 1996 to 1999, he was chief US economist at Deutsche Bank. While there, Carson was named to the Institutional Investor All-Star Team for Fixed Income and ranked as one of Best Analysts and Economists by The Global Investor Fixed Income Survey. He began his professional career in 1977 as a staff economist for the chief economist’s office in the US Department of Commerce, where he was designated the department’s representative at the Council on Wage and Price Stability during President Carter’s voluntary wage and price guidelines program. In 1979, Carson joined General Motors as an analyst. He held a variety of roles at GM, including chief forecaster for North America and chief analyst in charge of production recommendations for the Truck Group. From 1981 to 1986, Carson served as vice president and senior economist for the Capital Markets Economics Group at Merrill Lynch. In 1986, he joined Chemical Bank; he later became its chief economist. From 1992 to 1996, Carson served as chief economist at Dean Witter, where he sat on the investment-policy and stock-selection committees.   He received his BA and MA from Youngstown State University and did his PhD coursework at George Washington University. Honorary Doctorate Degree, Business Administration Youngstown State University 2016. Location: New York.

    More in Author Profile »

More Viewpoints